The political economy of paternalism Kai A. Konrad
By: Konrad, Kai Andreas
.
Material type: 





Item type | Current location | Home library | Call number | Status | Date due | Barcode |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Artículos | IEF | IEF | OP 1443/2024/201/1/2-1 (Browse shelf) | Available | OP 1443/2024/201/1/2-1 |
Browsing IEF Shelves Close shelf browser
No cover image available | No cover image available | No cover image available | No cover image available | No cover image available | No cover image available | No cover image available | ||
OP 1443/2024/200/1/2 -3 Investment incentives attract foreign direct investment | OP 1443/2024/200/3/4 Public Choice | OP 1443/2024/201/1/2 Public Choice | OP 1443/2024/201/1/2-1 The political economy of paternalism | OP 1443/2024/201/1/2-2 Enhancing voluntary contributions in a public goods economy via a minimum individual contribution level | OP 1443/2024/201/3/4 Public Choice | OP 1443/2024/201/3/4-1 Markets and knowledge commons: Is there a difference between private and community governance of markets? |
Bibliografía
Some citizens place a high value on making decisions for themselves. Other citizens are happy to delegate decisions to a government agency. Such differences in political attitudes to paternalism can be explained in a strict rational-choice model with citizens’ heterogeneous tastes in the economic sphere. Citizens with more eccentric tastes and with high decision-making abilities tend to favor a libertarian regime. If majority preferences matter, heterogeneity in economic preferences and analytical abilities can also explain whether the political regime is more paternalist or more libertarian. As decision-making skills are a learnable capability, the strategic complementarity of individuals’ investments in analytical skills in the context of political regime outcomes suggests a feedback mechanism that can cause multiple expectations equilibria. Both a libertarian regime or a paternalist regime can emerge.
There are no comments for this item.