000 | 02025nab#a2200313#c#4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
003 | IEF | ||
005 | 20180219161021.0 | ||
008 | 170518s2017 DEU|| #####0 b|ENG|u | ||
040 | _aIEF | ||
041 | _aENG | ||
100 | 1 |
_aJessen, Robin _965377 |
|
245 |
_aGetting the por to work _b three welfare - increasing reforms for a busy Germany _c Robin Jessen, Davud Rostam - Afschar and Viktor Steiner |
||
260 | _c2017 | ||
500 | _aDisponible también en línea a través de la Biblioteca del Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Resumen. Conclusión. Bibliografía. | ||
650 | 4 |
_aRENTAS BAJAS _93605 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aRENTA BÁSICA _959338 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aTIPO LINEAL _948539 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aIMPUESTOS _947460 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aPOBREZA _948038 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aALEMANIA _925193 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aMODELOS DE SIMULACIÓN _947773 |
|
520 | _aWe study three budget-neutral reforms of the German tax and transfer system designedto improve work incentives for people with low incomes: a feasible flat tax reform thatprovides a basic income equal to the current level of the means-tested unemploymentbenefit, and two alternative reforms that involve employment subsidies to stimulateparticipation and full-time work, respectively. We estimate labor supply reactions andwelfare effects using a microsimulation model based on household data from the Socio-Economic Panel and a structural labor supply model. We find that all three reforms increaselabor supply in the first decile of the income distribution. The flat tax scenario reduces overall labor supply by about 5%; the reform designed to increase participation reduces labor supply by 1%; the reform that provides incentives to work full-time has negligible effects on overall labor supply. With equal welfare weights, aggregate welfare gains are realizable under all three reforms. | ||
700 | 1 |
_aRostam Afschar, Davud _965378 |
|
700 | 1 |
_aSteiner, Viktor _953430 |
|
773 | 0 |
_tFinanzArchiv _w21244 _gv. 73, n. 1, March 2017, p. 1-41 |
|
942 | _cART | ||
942 | _z147951 | ||
999 |
_c61352 _d61352 |