000 | 01646nab a2200229 c 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
999 |
_c150131 _d150131 |
||
003 | ES-MaIEF | ||
005 | 20250116153955.0 | ||
007 | ta | ||
008 | 250115t2024 uk |||||o|||| 00| 0 eng d | ||
040 |
_aES-MaIEF _bspa _cES-MaIEF |
||
100 |
_924061 _aKonrad, Kai Andreas |
||
245 | 1 | 4 |
_aThe political economy of paternalism _c Kai A. Konrad |
504 | _aBibliografĂa | ||
520 | _aSome citizens place a high value on making decisions for themselves. Other citizens are happy to delegate decisions to a government agency. Such differences in political attitudes to paternalism can be explained in a strict rational-choice model with citizens’ heterogeneous tastes in the economic sphere. Citizens with more eccentric tastes and with high decision-making abilities tend to favor a libertarian regime. If majority preferences matter, heterogeneity in economic preferences and analytical abilities can also explain whether the political regime is more paternalist or more libertarian. As decision-making skills are a learnable capability, the strategic complementarity of individuals’ investments in analytical skills in the context of political regime outcomes suggests a feedback mechanism that can cause multiple expectations equilibria. Both a libertarian regime or a paternalist regime can emerge. | ||
650 | 4 |
_948576 _aTOMA DE DECISIONES |
|
650 | 4 |
_925834 _aANALISIS ECONOMICO |
|
650 | 4 |
_aECONOMIA _943074 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aREGIMENES POLITICOS _948227 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aSOCIOLOGIA POLITICA _948477 |
|
773 | 0 |
_9172788 _oOP 1443/2024/201/1/2 _tPublic Choice _w(IEF)124378 _x 0048-5829 _g vol. 201, n.1-2 (octubre 2024) p. 61-81 |
|
942 | _cART |