000 | 02072nab#a2200277#c#4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
003 | IEF | ||
005 | 20180219170112.0 | ||
008 | 171214s2017 USA|| #####0 b|ENG|u | ||
040 | _aIEF | ||
041 | _aENG | ||
100 | 1 |
_aHeathcote, Jonathan _916184 |
|
245 |
_aOptimal Tax Progressivity _b An Analytical Framework _c Jonathan Heathcote,Kjetil Storesletten, Giovanni L. Violante |
||
260 | _c2017 | ||
500 | _aDisponible también en línea a través de la Biblioteca del Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Resumen. Bibliografía. | ||
650 | 4 |
_aIMPOSICION OPTIMA _97978 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aIMPUESTOS _947460 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aPROGRESIVIDAD _948160 |
|
650 | 4 |
_aMODELOS ECONOMETRICOS _947776 |
|
520 | _aWhat shapes the optimal degree of progressivity of the tax and transfer system? On the one hand, a progressive tax system can counteract inequality in initial conditions and substitute for imperfect private insurance against idiosyncratic earnings risk. On the other hand, progressivity reduces incentives to work and toinvest in skills, distortions that are especially costly when the government mustfinance public goods. We develop a tractable equilibrium model that features all of these trade-offs. The analytical expressions we derive for social welfare deliver a transparent understanding of how preference, technology, and market structure parameters influence the optimal degree of progressivity. A calibration for the U.S. economy indicates that endogenous skill investment, flexible labor supply, and the desire to finance government purchases play quantitatively similar roles in limitingoptimal progressivity. In a version of the model where poverty constrains skill investment, optimal progressivity is close to the U.S. value. An empirical analysis on cross-country data offers support to the theory. | ||
700 | 1 |
_aStoresletten, Kjetil _91282 |
|
700 | 1 |
_aViolante, Giovanni L. _954041 |
|
773 | 0 |
_tThe Quarterly Journal of Economics _w55704 _gv. 132, n. 532, issue 4, November 2017, p. 1693-1754 |
|
942 | _cART | ||
942 | _z149269 | ||
999 |
_c102983 _d102983 |